[RRE]reading list

From: Phil Agre (pagreat_private)
Date: Thu May 15 2003 - 18:00:03 PDT

  • Next message: Phil Agre: "[RRE]The Practical Republic"

    Philip Mirowski, Machine Dreams: Economics Becomes a Cyborg Science,
    Cambridge: Cambridge University Press, 2002.  Chapter 1 available at:
    http://commons.somewhere.com/rre/2001/RRE.Machine.Dreams.html
    This is a tremendously interesting work of 20th century intellectual
    history, a thorough and robustly argued narrative of the tension
    within the field of economics over the nature and role of information.
    Neoclassical economics, as Mirowski argued in his book "More Heat
    Than Light", was invented through an analogy with early 19th century
    physics that assumes that perfect information is effectively available 
    to everyone.  Although the neoclassical school probably remains a
    majority of the profession, several information-centered schools have
    arisen.  The central figure in Mirowski's book is John von Neumann,
    whose work in inventing the digital computer and game theory, among
    other things, seems even more important after reading Mirowski than
    we had already heard it was.  Mirowski combines an extremely strong
    knowledge of the foundations of economics with a serious talent for
    institutional history, with the result that every page practically
    glows in the dark with remarkable ideas about the history of both
    economics and computing.
    
    Eric Brousseau, EDI and inter-firm relationships: Toward a
    standardization of coordination processes?, Information Economics
    and Policy 6, 1994, pages 319-347.  This is a careful and thoroughly
    argued paper about the conditions under which companies can coordinate
    their activities with their suppliers in an automated fashion using
    electronic data interchange (EDI).  EDI is B2B online commerce avant
    la lettre -- a type of business-to-business communications protocol
    that requires the businesses to invest considerable effort up-front
    to articulate a vocabulary of possible circumstances they might need
    to communicate about and a set of policies for acting automatically
    on any EDI message when it arrives.  EDI has a reputation for being
    cumbersome, but in reality what is cumbersome is the intrinsic problem
    that EDI is supposed to solve.  Brousseau's argument is that EDI
    is useless -- that is, not worth the considerable effort of setting
    it up -- in industries such as petroleum refining where operations
    change only infrequently and within a small and well-defined space
    of possibilities, and that it is also useless in industries such as
    construction in which projects differ immensely among themselves and
    often change in major ways when they are halfway along.  This kind
    of article is immensely useful because it forestalls overgeneralization.
    Every industry needs to be analyzed on its own terms.  In particular,
    an analysis like Brousseau's can be helpful in determining the best
    division of labor between automatic protocols like EDI and actual
    communication among human beings, whether in the customer-supplier
    relationship or elsewhere.
    
    Stephen S. Cohen and Gary Fields, Social capital and capital gains:
    An examination of social capital in Silicon Valley, in Martin Kenney,
    ed, Understanding Silicon Valley: The Anatomy of an Entrepreneurial
    Region, Stanford: Stanford University Press, 2000.  This useful
    paper uses Silicon Valley as an example in proposing a new theory of
    social capital.  Social capital has been understood in terms of social
    networks: the more people know one another, the more possibilities
    arise for entrepreneurship, whether civic or economic.  Cohen and
    Fields build on this conventional theory by describing the unique
    ensemble of institutions that have made the social networks of Silicon
    Valley so productive.  These institutions include the great research
    universities, government research and development policies, venture
    capital, stock options, and the specific nature of the computer
    industry.  This theory is useful because it explains why the Silicon
    Valley model might not be applicable elsewhere.  A different industry,
    with different kinds of products, may require a different ensemble
    of institutions.  Thus even an industrial region such as the computer
    industry of suburban Boston might end up seeming very different from
    Silicon Valley once their respective institutions have been analyzed.
    The next step is to evolve a method for determining what industries
    might prosper in what kinds of regions, and what kinds of institutional
    innovations might be necessary in particular contexts.
    
    Bruno Latour, Social theory and the study of computerized work sites,
    in Wanda Orlikowski, Geoff Walsham, Matthew R. Jones, and Janice
    I. DeGross, eds, Information Technology and Changes in Organizational
    Work, London: Chapman and Hall, 1996.  This short paper is an exercise
    in an important project: understanding computers as artefacts that are
    densely knitted into sprawling, diverse networks.  The point is not
    that people, computers, and other artefacts interact a lot.  Rather,
    every element of the network impresses some of its properties on the
    others.  Human work skills, for example, are inscribed into computers,
    whether literally in the form of expert systems or in simpler and
    more various ways as human attributes are taken into account through
    the design process.  Computers and other artefacts likewise become
    impressed on people through, inter alia, cognitive processes that
    routinely depend on the availability of computerized representations,
    for example when checking the status of one's train on the departure
    board upon walking into a train station.  For this reason, Latour
    argues that we should think of people, computers, and other artefacts
    as being distributed, and their attributes as continuously circulating
    through the sociotechnical networks that generations of entrepreneurs
    have woven into our lives.
    
    Roy Rosenzweig, Wizards, bureaucrats, warriors, and hackers: Writing
    the history of the Internet, American Historical Review 103(5),
    1998, pages 1530-1552.  This is a useful review essay by a historian
    on several popular and scholarly books about the beginnings of the
    Internet, considered as historiography.  Its central topic is the
    diverse contexts in which the Internet's rise needs to be analyzed,
    and particularly the dialectic of military-establishment and counter-
    cultural contributions to the Internet and earlier networks such as
    ARPANET and USENET.  Some of these histories concentrate on individuals
    -- understandably so, given that some remarkable individuals were
    involved in the story.  But remarkable individuals can be found in
    many places and times, and so an emphasis on individuals does not
    tell us the conditions under which any individuals at all could be
    capable of those particular feats.  Those conditions include the R&D
    policies of the US military in a particular window of time during
    the Cold War.  They also include the international politics by which
    the TCP/IP protocols, improbably in historical terms, rose to their
    current place as a generally accepted standard.  USENET, by contrast,
    was the work of volunteers and hobbyists, many of them motivated by
    the democratic themes of the counterculture.  Yet even that opposition
    between the military Internet and democratic USENET simplifies
    the history as well, for example in regard to the early Internet's
    self-consciously informal culture and the military funding of many
    of the sites that ran USENET.  Rosenzweig thus calls for research
    into the cultural context of all of these networks, for example in
    the rise of a libertarianism that was surprisingly able to reconcile
    the counterculture with Reaganism.
    
    Mark Casson, An entrepreneurial theory of the firm, in Enterprise and
    Leadership: Studies on Firms, Markets and Networks, Cheltenham, UK:
    Elgar, 2000.  Mark Casson is an economist who studies, among other
    things, the effect of information flows on firms and industries.
    In this particular paper he describes the role of the entrepreneur
    in identifying "missing markets", that is, opportunities to connect
    production factors such as skilled labor with consumers through
    a new intermediary, the entrepreneur's firm.  This whole question
    has been more or less neglected in the mainstream of neoclassical
    economics, which emphasizes allocation over innovation and imagines
    markets to be already perfect or nearly so.  In particular, Casson,
    in common with many other outstanding economists of information and
    institutions, understands the firm as an active market-maker rather
    than a passive taker of prices.  He devotes several highly intelligent
    pages to what he calls "synthesis": the process by which competing
    entrepreneurs gather information in various places throughout the
    economy and attempt to identify the entrepreneurial opportunity that
    interrelates them.  He notes, for example, that an entrepreneur must
    generally have two quite different talents: noticing new opportunities
    through networking and capitalizing on those opportunities by building
    a firm.  This is because the information that a given opportunity
    exists cannot easily be bought and sold -- even a slight hint as to
    the location of the opportunity will be enough for many other skilled
    entrepreneurs to steal the idea.  It is remarkable that economics has
    gone so long without a serious theory of entrepreneurship.  Part of
    the problem is that economics has long emphasized physical goods over
    intangible ones.  Information has quite different properties from most
    physical goods, and in work like Casson's we can start to appreciate
    just how much difference these differences make in our understanding
    of economic and other institutions.
    



    This archive was generated by hypermail 2b30 : Thu May 15 2003 - 18:40:43 PDT