[RRE]a case study of the wired world

From: Phil Agre (pagreat_private)
Date: Sun Jun 24 2001 - 15:33:54 PDT

  • Next message: Phil Agre: "[RRE]Machine Dreams"

    =-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=
    This message was forwarded through the Red Rock Eater News Service (RRE).
    You are welcome to send the message along to others but please do not use
    the "redirect" option.  For information about RRE, including instructions
    for (un)subscribing, see http://dlis.gseis.ucla.edu/people/pagre/rre.html
    =-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=-=
    
    
      The Wired Car in the Wired World
    
      Phil Agre
      http://dlis.gseis.ucla.edu/pagre/
    
      Version of 24 June 2001
    
      4200 words
    
    
    As the news goes by in its daily doses, it's easy to lose track of the
    patterns.  So let us take a moment and connect some dots.  Let us take
    a single, familiar site -- the car -- and trace the amazing variety
    of institutions that intend to wire that site in one way or another.
    Most of us, especially if we are Americans, drive a car all the
    time, and we recognize that the car is a point of intersection for
    many institutional agendas.  At any given time, most of us have at
    least one bureaucratic hassle in progress relating to our cars, be
    it buying, selling, registration, repair, insurance, law enforcement,
    parking, you name it.  Every one of those hassles is organized by an
    institution, every institution has more or less the same components:
    several layers of law, a sprawling map of interested parties,
    an information infrastructure, nonobvious interactions between
    governments and markets, people who specialize in working all of the
    angles, and a culture of popular resistance and vigilantism.
    
    Institutions exist largely to solve informational problems, and as
    information technology changes it stands to reason that institutions
    will change as well.  Institutions, however, are not driven in any
    direct way by technology.  Institutions are political, and they
    change through a complicated and diffuse sort of collective bargaining
    among the various stakeholder groups.  Some groups are more organized
    than others, of course, and the new technologies create opportunities
    that each stakeholder group can either seize or fumble.  Once the
    smoke clears, the institutions will settle into a new form -- a form
    that could have turned out differently if, for example, unorganized
    stakeholders had gotten their act together to shape the technology in
    some different direction.
    
    As the example of car illustrate, however, institutions do not evolve
    independently of one another.  Because every person is enmeshed in
    a wide variety of institutions, and because the institutions all
    operate on the same planet, all of the various institutional change
    processes intersect and overlap.  One good way to see the intersections
    and overlaps is to focus attention on a single object -- an object on
    which several changing institutions are all laying claims.  Such as,
    for example, the car.
    
    We can start someplace obvious, with law enforcement.  Now, a common
    pattern is that new technologies fit into existing institutional
    niches, not so much changing anything as amplifying things that were
    already going on.  For example, law enforcement organizations already
    have several kinds of incentives to enforce traffic laws.  But as
    the constituent technologies of various automatic enforcement schemes
    -- video cameras, data communications, image recognition -- become
    cheaper, automatic traffic enforcement can become widespread.  Of
    course, political backlash by drivers is a countervailing factor, and
    it is an empirical question (both for theorists and for the parties
    involved) which technologies produce which kinds of backlash in which
    kinds of political settings.  Radar enforcement of speed limits, for
    example, is regulated to a degree by drivers' complaints to elected
    representatives.  But representatives experience many pressures, and
    they get elected on bundles of issues, not just speed traps.  Now we
    have a new generation of enforcement technologies:
    
      http://www.guardianunlimited.co.uk/uk_news/story/0,3604,425344,00.html
    
      http://newsvote.bbc.co.uk/hi/english/uk/newsid_590000/590336.stm
    
    Britain is the leader here, as it is in many areas of advanced privacy
    invasion.  Deep-running traditions of deference, combined with the
    Thatcherite legacy of centrally organized obliteration of traditional
    institutions in the name of decentralization, combined with the
    New Labour strategy of occupying the entire political spectrum while
    stifling internal dissent, have made the UK into a free-fire zone
    of surveillance.  Of course, that wouldn't matter if technology were
    stable.  But now the UK is going to be a testing ground for a new
    generation of surveillance of technologies.  Cars are only one area,
    of course; the UK is also a leader in video cameras in public places,
    and is competing with the US in the area of financial surveillance.
    
    But law enforcement is not the only institution that has an interest
    in exerting control over cars and drivers.  I've long predicted that
    insurance companies will institute "lower" rates for people who agree
    to have their cars tracked (i.e., higher rates for people who don't,
    and since the people who drive to dangerous places will rationally
    opt out, privacy-lovers will be lumped with this high-risk group),
    and at least one company has experimented with GPS tracking of cars:
    
      http://www1.progressive.com/media_relations/Autograph.htm
    
    That experiment has ended, but we can expect others.  It's probably
    not worth doing as a stand-alone system, but once cars come equipped
    with GPS and data uplinks for other reasons, the incremental cost
    of tracking cars for insurance purposes will be minimal.  There
    are plenty of actuaries who would love to write the algorithm which
    consumes your locational information and produces a rating based
    on historical experience with insurance payouts to other drivers
    who have gone to similar places.  It will be possible to print
    risk maps showing that driving past location X at time Y costs $0.02
    in insurance, where driving past some other location at some other
    time costs $0.09.  Where will the red zones lie?  Notice that these
    red zones need not measure any intrinsic danger in the place itself.
    Rather, the statistics will pick up all kinds of correlations whose
    underlying causes may not be obvious.  If people who leave work at the
    factory early tend to get a drink on the way home, then the increased
    accident rates of the drinkers may spill onto other people who happen
    to drive past the factory gates at the early hour.  Of course, in
    theory it is in the insurance company's interest to separate out the
    variables.  But their data won't be infinite.
    
    It's not just insurance companies that have an interest in tracking
    cars, of course.  At least one rental car company is already doing so:
    
      http://www.zdnet.com/zdnn/stories/news/0,4586,2778752,00.html
    
    We're not just talking about theft recovery systems, which have been
    around for a long time, and which do not need to be activated unless
    the car has been reported stolen.  We're talking about continuous
    monitoring of the car's location, and potentially of many other
    aspects of the way you're using it.  The rental companies are in much
    the same position as the insurance companies; they want to charge
    their customers based on the risk they present.  They can easily put
    language in their form contracts that lets them bill your credit card
    automatically whenever the GPS device says you're speeding.
    
    The market does create countervailing forces.  Customers will shop
    for a bundle of features among different car rental companies, and
    included in that bundle will be contract terms about tracking and
    fines.  In the magical version of the market that economists theorize
    about, the result will be a market equilibrium in which customers
    decide how much tracking they are willing to put up with, in
    exchange for how much of a discount on the rental rate.  But in
    the real market, things are more complicated.  Form contracts take
    time to study and education to understand.  Customers may assume
    that they have legal protections that they they do not really have.
    The tracking information will probably have commercial value, and
    customers may not understand the consequences of that information
    circulating out in the world.
    
    Another institutional question is where roads come from.  One answer
    is that people pay taxes and then politicians and bureaucrats put
    roads down, with interest groups working both sides of the issue
    all the way.  In the idealized world of the economists, however,
    roads should be paid for by the people who use them.  Technology
    makes this vision more feasible by making it easier to collect tolls
    automatically, and the politics of automatic toll collection takes on
    an endless diversity of forms.  In Singapore, authoritarianism with
    high-tech characteristics allows the government to impose variable
    pricing on all of its roads, which in turn requires every car and
    driver to be integrated both legally and technologically into the
    market-making bureaucracy.  In California, various state and regional
    governments have been struggling with a plan to finance roads by
    letting the contractor collect tolls on them until they've made their
    money back.  This plan has generally been a disaster on account of the
    many devils in the details.  One such devil is usability:
    
      http://www.latimes.com/print/metro/20010624/t000052351.html
    
    Simply put, drivers don't use the toll roads because they find them
    confusing.  The roads don't have consistent rules about things like
    exact change, and people routinely get big penalty bills in the mail
    because they took the wrong exit or couldn't figure out how to use the
    toll system for the first time.  Now multiply this situation by dozens
    and you have the usability nightmare for all of the independently
    developed electronic systems that impinge on cars -- and that's just
    cars, not even counting all of the other machines we deal with all day.
    
    So far I have been emphasizing institutions that have bad reputations. 
    But my point is not that electronic wiring of cars is necessarily all
    bad.  A lot depends on how it is done.  Let us consider, for example,
    proposals for digital systems relating to traffic accidents.  I have
    mentioned that some theft-detection systems are unobjectionable since
    they are not activated unless the car is reported stolen.  Likewise,
    it is not so bad to have a device that incorporates an accelerometer,
    and that is activated automatically (only) when the device detects
    an acceleration of sufficient magnitude that injuries are likely.
    In those situations, the device could alert appropriate authorities
    and upload full details of the car, its position, and the identities
    and medical records of the car's owners.  Of course, one would want
    to be certain that the information was encrypted so it couldn't be
    intercepted by people who you don't want knowing about your traffic
    injuries.  Nonetheless, at the moment when the accelerometer trips,
    your desire for privacy normally declines rapidly relative to your
    desire for relevant people to know about the situation.  Here's a
    government report on the idea:
    
      http://www.nhtsa.dot.gov/cars/problems/studies/acns/champion.htm
    
    But then there's reality.  Reality, once again, is that these things
    tend not to happen as stand-alone systems, and stand-alone systems
    tend over time to be absorbed into more general architectures.
    So consider the case of GM's OnStar.  When you get into an accident,
    OnStar reports the accident to the authorities.  But where the USDOT
    was writing from the idealized perspective of physicians and highway
    safety experts, OnStar is trying to be a generalized platform for the
    delivery of electronic services to GM drivers.
    
      http://www.business2.com/content/magazine/indepth/2001/02/26/26993
    
    So, recently, a GM driver got into an accident and decided to make a
    run for it, only to be tracked down using information that his OnStar
    had provided:
    
      http://catless.ncl.ac.uk/Risks/21.46.html#subj4
    
    Of course, nobody likes hit-and-run drivers.  Once these systems are
    in place, however, their function starts to creep, and we tolerate
    function creep because at each step we can identify a bad guy who
    is going to get his comeuppance as a result.  But who else is OnStar
    telling on, and where does it stop?  The main tradition of computer
    system design is inherently privacy-invasive in the sense that it
    assigns identifiers to everyone and everything in sight, and once a
    system is built this way it's very hard to stop it from sliding down
    the slippery slope of ever-broadened functionality.
    
    As electronic systems proliferate, moreover, security attacks become
    ever more likely.  The great majority of system designers live in an
    idealized world without hackers, and they haven't gotten it through
    their heads that any security hack can be packaged in a black box and
    disseminated by the thousand.  So take the case of wireless "keys"
    that unlock cars at a distance.  Those things are just asking to be
    spoofed, and history shows that designers always underestimate the
    likelihood of such attacks.
    
      http://www.newscientist.com/ns/981205/newsstory6.html
    
    Imagine the consequences as your car goes on the Internet.  We're
    used to viruses in our desktop computers and we've heard about viruses
    in our palmtops.  Next we'll have viruses in our cars, and then we'll
    have them in our pacemakers.  Wireless communications is especially
    asking for it, and a public-spirited lawyer once mailed me a package
    of documents from a California Air Resources Board plan to equip all
    new cars with a device that would upload the car's identification
    number and emissions equipment status *in plaintext* whenever it was
    pinged by a roadside transponder.  Wrong!
    
    Lots of money are at stake in the internal workings of your car, and
    the role of electronics, which is already enormous -- from globally
    networked teams of designers using CAD tools to anti-lock brakes
    and computerized fuel-injection -- will only grow.  The laboratories
    of advanced experimentation are in auto racing, where computerization
    has grown so extreme that cars routinely "crash" in a software sense:
    
      http://catless.ncl.ac.uk/Risks/21.48.html#subj4
    
    A car whose operating system has crashed is not only a joke, but a
    serious danger to other drivers.  And that's not even an environment
    where competition has gone as far as the sorts of electronic warfare
    that are taken for granted in military contexts, or that ought to be
    taken for granted in a world of script-kiddie thieves.  Electronically
    hyped race cars can also be dangerous to their drivers as a result of
    their sheer speed -- race car drivers have recently started blacking
    out on sharp curves.
    
      http://catless.ncl.ac.uk/Risks/21.49.html#subj14
    
    The politics of automotive technology is especially hard-fought in the
    context of environmental issues.  When Al Gore made the commonplace
    observation that the internal combustion engine's days are numbered,
    Republicans twisted this into a generalized attack on the family car.
    The fact that these reptiles expected such a lie to work indicates
    the magnitude of the interests and the depth of feeling around basic
    issues of automotive technologies.  Digital control will be central to
    whichever technology succeeds internal combustion, but no alternative
    will be possible until a substantial infrastructure is built.  This
    has been one of the vulnerabilities of electric cars, which California
    has been compelling the auto companies to build.  It hasn't worked, of
    course, because the auto companies have hundreds of ways of subverting
    the very long learning curve required to establish economies of scale
    and complementary services for the new technology.  Passive aggression
    is quite enough.
    
      http://www.newtimesla.com/issues/2001-06-21/feature.html/page1.html
    
    They can thus complain that the technology is "expensive", which of
    course it will be so long as electric cars remain a small percentage
    of the cars on the road.
    
    Now let us move to the world of electronic gear in the interior of the
    car.  There is a huge amount of action in this area:
    
      http://www.digitalcar.sae.org/digitalcar/
    
    I've mentioned that GM wants to make OnStar into a general platform
    for delivering services into cars.  As with the marketing of many
    new technologies, they are introducing the services first into their
    high-end cars.  So it is not surprising that stock trading is high on
    their list of extended OnStar services.  Some of these services will
    be standard equipment, so to speak, whereas others will be offered
    by subscription or whatever.  That dividing line will be determined
    by marketing considerations and by the economics of the service.
    The important thing is the generalized platform, which will rapidly
    come down in price and itself become standard equipment on all cars.
    And so naturally one part of their long-term picture is to push
    advertising into cars.  You read that right:
    
      http://news.cnet.com/news/0-1014-202-6352568-0.html
    
    And that's not even including advertisements on electronic billboards
    along the side of the road:
    
      http://catless.ncl.ac.uk/Risks/21.45.html#subj2
    
    These networked advertising systems will be technological wonders.
    Think of banner ads in your car, alongside the highway, everywhere.
    Of course, banner ads on the Web are one of those technologies that
    was overpromised because lots of people couldn't tell the difference
    between the idealized market and the grotty realities of markets as
    it exists right now.  But in the automotive environment, huge amounts
    of personal information really will be available for the customization
    of advertisements.  How about having ads pop up for every business
    you approach along the roadway, each of them tailored to your own
    demographics?  If your car knows you've been driving for ten hours
    straight, then you can guess what kinds of ads will pop up.  Now
    imagine the automatic capture and aggregation of the demographics of
    the drivers along a given roadway.  The demographics of that moving
    audience could be posted automatically on the Internet, and then
    advertisers could bid in real time to put their own presentation on
    the roadside billboard.  One-minute intervals would be about right.
    You could then have ads that appear on successive billboards as your
    little cohort of drivers makes its way along.
    
    It is well-understood that these ads can be distracting, especially
    when they are bright and animated, and the relevant public relations
    departments are gearing up to "manage" this "issue", for example with
    advertising campaigns encouraging people to drive responsibly and pay
    attention.  These ad campaigns, pioneered by cell phone companies, are
    aimed as much at regulators and legislators as they are at drivers;
    they are part of an elaborate professional practice of looking like
    you're doing something about a problem without sacrificing any of the
    profits that you enjoy from it.
    
    The ads are one part of a big picture.  America is the land of
    disastrous automobile-driven urban planning, or non-planning as
    the case may be, and nobody is surprised that cars are increasingly
    turning into apartments with wheels.  The pioneers were the mobile
    workers, like salespeople and truckers, who work out of their
    vehicles more or less full-time.  Wireless data networking kicks
    the "car office" into high gear:
    
      http://www.nytimes.com/2001/06/14/technology/14CARS.html?pagewanted=all
    
    The next step is the car-centered entertainment center, especially for
    children who would otherwise be constantly asking "are we there yet"?
    
      http://washingtonpost.com/wp-dyn/articles/A38329-2001Jun23.html
    
    The first generation of these in-car technologies are more or less
    transplanted versions of the home technologies, but we can expect that
    future versions will be designed specifically for the car environment.
    
    Now, from one perspective these technologies represent the next step
    in an already well-established trend whereby everyone becomes isolated
    in their own personal media zone.  It's "bedroom culture" generalized
    to the back seat of the car.  Shouldn't everyone be sitting around
    the fire having deep conversations and teaching their grandchildren
    the folktales that they learned from their grandparents?  Well, that's
    hard to do when you're in a car.  Having your kids in the back seat
    of the car while you're driving was already an impossible situation:
    enough togetherness to be annoying, but not enough to be useful.
    Children, after all, feed on their parents' attention, and attention
    is precisely what a driver doesn't have.  Back-seat entertainment
    systems aren't destroying any quality time; instead they are bringing
    out the inherent logic that already existed in the situation: the
    car as the technological reification of the atomized society, with
    everyone knitted into a welter of institutions that pick them up
    and haul them from one place to the next with no special concern for
    geography or relationships.
    
    Again the picture is not all bad.  Bill Mitchell observes that the
    same digital networks that allow people and things to be connected at
    a distance also allow people to strengthen connections that do require
    geographic proximity.  People are somewhat more free to live where
    they want.  Some visionaries had predicted that this would lead to an
    increased gentrification of rural areas, and some of that is surely
    happening.  Just as important, though, is a renewed gentrification
    in industrial-world inner cities.  Urban density has the great virtue
    of creating critical mass for services that require both geographic
    proximity and economies of scale, and we can only hope that digital
    technologies will be put to use in making dense urban centers more
    livable, for example through computerized vibrational analysis that
    makes for quiet compressors.  Then maybe we Americans be more like
    Europeans and get rid of our cars altogether, and Europeans can stop
    becoming like Americans and get rid of their brand new cars before
    it's too late.
    
    In any case, we have hardly begun to reckon with the huge world of
    institutions that want to get their electronic hooks into our cars.
    A guy who designs atom-bomb powered X-ray lasers at a US national
    laboratory once mock-ruefully told me that "the biggest problem with
    the modern world is that we now have institutions that are built
    on derivatives" -- that is, institutions with a vested interest in
    changing the world as much as possible, not randomly of course but
    in ways that create a continued demand for their own particular kind
    of work.  Ordinary people's lives are a hassle in large part because
    of all the experts and social climbers who get ahead only if they are
    changing things whether they need changing or not, and now there is
    a whole world of intersecting institutions that have an interest in
    changing the technology of transportation.  Here we have one version
    of the standard sales-pitch:
    
      http://www.brook.edu/es/urban/ITS.htm
    
    Endless hundreds of white papers and PowerPoint presentations have
    been devoted to disseminating this sales pitch, which is the symbolic
    foundation of numerous companies and careers, particularly in this
    relatively early phase when "intelligent transportation" is generating
    little actual revenue.  Intelligent transportation, so-called, really
    began as a push to find civilian uses for military technologies at
    the end of the Cold War, when everyone assumed for some foolish reason
    that society would be demilitarized.  Alright, it was more complex
    than that, as all of the various interests converged from their
    own angles into a loose, baggy coalition.  But the vision was very
    much driven by the traditional transportation bureaucracies, such
    as the ones who have now built grandiose traffic monitoring command
    post headquarters for themselves.  Whole institutions are devoted to
    collecting and archiving information about traffic for purposes like
    maintenance, planning, and safety:
    
      http://www.traffic-records.org/
    
      http://www.itsdocs.fhwa.dot.gov/jpodocs/repts_pr/9pj01!.pdf
    
      http://conferences.iee.org.uk/RTIC/
    
    Much of this information is anonymous, of course, but that's because
    it is collected with the primitive old analog methods of data capture.
    Modern data comes in fully identified digital records, and most people
    hardly realize how established the interests in transportation data-
    collection are.  We'll find out when identified data becomes the rule
    rather than the exception.
    
    The world of "intelligent transportation" is enormous.  Here is the
    main US organization:
    
      http://www.itsa.org/
    
    Here are some directories of projects:
    
      http://www.itsdocs.fhwa.dot.gov/\JPODOCS\CATALOG/13464.html
    
      http://www.itsdocs.fhwa.dot.gov/\JPODOCS\REPTS_TE/13338.pdf
    
      http://www.computer.org/intelligent/articles/intelligent_vehicles.htm
    
    Here are some of the conferences:
    
      http://ewh.ieee.org/tc/its/2001/
    
      http://www.itsworldcongress.org/home.htm
    
    (The ITS America conference happened in Florida earlier this month.)
    
    And here is a summary of conclusions from ten years of federally-funded
    projects:
    
      http://www.itsdocs.fhwa.dot.gov/\JPODOCS\REPTS_TE/@9W01!.PDF
    
    A problem with most of these projects is that they are starting from
    a technology base that's too primitive, and so they aren't informed
    by the decentralized ethos of the Internet.  In the end these 1980's
    technologies aren't good for all that much, and the emphasis has
    shifted from the roadways to the vehicles.
    
      http://www.techreview.com/magazine/jul01/schmidtall.asp
    
    A road is a road, pretty much.  But as information technology
    platforms become standardized and universal, the world will change
    a lot.  Cars and their drivers are embedded in a tremendous variety
    of institutions, and new electronic technologies will allow every
    one of those embeddings to become more present, more continual, more
    informationally complex, and more integrated with one another.  The
    web of institutionally organized relationships into which we are all
    knitted will become more tightly woven.  None of these relationships
    are all bad, or else it would be relatively easy to get rid of them.
    But neither are they inevitable in their design.  The fact is that
    few if any of the functionalities I have described require people
    to be identified; nearly all of them, in other words, can be provided
    anonymously.
    
    The point generalizes.  Every institutional relationship, whether
    buyer/seller, insurer/insured, legislator/citizen, or cop/driver, has
    its architecture.  That architecture is a product of history -- that
    is, of conflict and compromise.  The architecture is partly legal,
    partly technical, and partly cognitive and cultural.  Institutional
    architectures rarely spring full-blown from nowhere; most often
    they are shaped incrementally, and the power of each stakeholder
    group to shape an institution tomorrow will be influenced by the
    way the institution works today.  We keep hearing that computers are
    revolutionary, but the opposite is more nearly true: the conventional
    way to design a computer is to start with the existing institutional
    order and inscribe it into machinery.  But we don't have to design
    our technology that way, or our lives.  The technology really is
    value-neutral to a great extent.  It's a matter of choice.
    
    What values do we choose to inscribe into the technologies and
    institutions of transportation in the future?  We'll express
    our choices in many ways: through politics, through the market,
    by subverting the system, and in the ways we imagine our options.
    Contradictory as it seems, we need a form of imagination that
    is grounded in reality.  Look closely at any of these incipient
    technological-slash-institutional projects and you'll see a lot
    of reality that isn't imagined in the beautifully simplified forms
    of imagination of the past.
    
    end
    



    This archive was generated by hypermail 2b30 : Sun Jun 24 2001 - 15:51:32 PDT