[RRE]reading list

From: Phil Agre (pagreat_private)
Date: Fri May 09 2003 - 18:21:10 PDT

  • Next message: Phil Agre: "[RRE]reading list"

    I think the following papers are excellent and I encourage everyone
    to read them.
    
    Wes Sharrock and Graham Button, Empirical investigations: Practical
    sociological reasoning in the work of engineers, in Geoffrey
    C. Bowker, Susan Leigh Star, William Turner, and Les Gasser, eds,
    Social Science, Technical Systems and Cooperative Work: Beyond
    the Great Divide, Mahwah, NJ: Erlbaum, 1997.  It is often held that
    social scientists and technical people have trouble working together.
    They use different languages and methods, study different problems,
    identify results in different ways, and so on.  Sharrock and Button,
    however, argue that engineers are actually to a large extent practical
    sociologists.  Through their case studies of real engineers at work,
    they describe engineers engaged in situated deliberations of their
    user communities, the institutional dynamics of their firms, and
    their own processes of work, both when it is happening and especially
    in review afterward.  This reasoning is driven not by research agendas
    but by the necessity of anticipating and managing contingencies while
    working against a deadline and cooperating with people from other
    professional groups.  The objects of design are thoroughly affected
    by social processes, and Sharrock and Button describe some of the
    detailed work through which this happens.
    
    Nathan Rosenberg, Why in America?, in Exploring the Black Box:
    Technology, Economics, and History, Cambridge: Cambridge University
    Press, 1994.  This short, remarkable paper offers an explanation of
    an important historical phenomenon: the reason why mass manufacturing
    based on standardized products and methods, and particularly
    interchangeable parts, first arose in the United States.  A rapidly
    growing population led to the rapidly increasing demand which,
    as Adam Smith argued, leads to an increased division of labor.
    New transportation infrastructures such as canals and railroads also
    increased the effective size of the market.  The heavily agricultural
    nature of the society meant that consumers generally had the
    same needs, thus greatly increasing the returns to standardization
    and favoring the simplicity of mass manufactured products over the
    customized fanciness of artisanal products.  The abundance of natural
    resources and relative and capital rewarded automated manufacturing,
    which in its early days did not use such resources efficiently.
    As markets become increasingly global, Smith's argument implies that
    the division of labor is likely to increase even further.  Rosenberg's
    work is likely to help in reasoning about the changes in production
    and consumption that result.
    
    Fred W. Riggs, Bureaucracy and viable constitutionalism, in Abdo
    I. Baaklini and Helen Desfosses, eds, Designs for Democratic
    Stability: Studies in Viable Constitutionalism, Armonk, NY: Sharpe,
    1997.  I am very interested in what I call partial theories: theories
    that start from a single simple idea and use that idea to explain as
    much as they possibly can.  These theories can persuade their authors
    or readers that they are entirely self-sufficient, and that no other
    theories will ever be needed.  People can spend their whole lives
    working on such theories and ignoring all others.  At the same time,
    partial theories, especially when compared and contrasted a half dozen
    at a time, can be usefully taken as starting points for other, more
    complex theories.  In this paper, Fred Riggs presents a remarkably
    valuable partial theory of the success and failure of democratic
    governments, starting with the relationship between the legislature
    and the administrative bureaucracy.  A bureaucracy that is too strong
    is incompatible with democracy, and one that is too weak cannot
    do its job and is certain to be taken over by particular interests.
    Riggs taxonomizes various kinds of bureaucrats: mandarins, retainers,
    military officers, professionals, transients, and so on, depending
    on their respective structural relationships and career paths.
    He argues that the United States is distinctive in its transition
    historically from a retainer to a career bureaucracy -- a transition
    that might be undergoing some reversal today.  His argument is
    extremely helpful in understanding, for example, why Latin American
    polities have had so much trouble becoming democratic despite
    the formal analogies between their constitutions and that of the
    United States.  In short, this is an exemplary work of institutional
    theorizing, and no work on the role of information technology in
    institutional change can explain much unless it analyzes institutions
    on this sort of level among others.
    
    Stephen R. Barley, The alignment of technology and structure through
    roles and networks, Administrative Science Quarterly 35(1), 1990,
    pages 61-103.  This is a very impressive study of the way that
    a social system -- the diagnostic department of a hospital --
    reorganized itself after adopting a new technology -- CT scanning.
    Central to the story is knowledge and the ways that knowledge affects
    how people from different professional backgrounds work together from
    day to day.  Knowledge is a valuable form of capital, and changing
    distributions of knowledge go a long way to explaining the relative
    positions of groups.  In the case of the hospital, these relative
    positions rapidly turned into a social system.  Divisions of labor
    changed in other ways as well.  All of these arguments are grounded
    both in detailed study of interactions among individuals, for example
    in the kinds of formal and informal teaching and learning that take
    place between individuals from different groups, and in analyses
    of social networks.  These social dynamics depended heavily on
    the detailed workings of the technology, as well as on the social
    structure as it existed before the technology arrived.  Although
    I find his theory of social roles a little clumsy, overall this is
    an outstanding example of the ways that qualitative and quantitative
    methods can be combined to study the interaction between technology
    and social structure on multiple levels.
    
    Bruno Latour, On interobjectivity, Mind, Culture and Activity 3(4),
    1996, pages 228-245.  Bruno Latour is a rare animal -- a French
    philosopher who grounds his philosophy in fieldwork.  His work
    concerns the ways that people and their artifacts are knitted
    into networks.  In this paper, he discusses the ways that societies
    use artifacts to structure the contexts in which people interact.
    Dealing with a teller at a bank, one might identify the interaction
    as a "local" phenomenon, as distinct from the "global" phenomena
    of the economy or society as a whole.  But the bank, as well as the
    customer and teller, are very much located in networks.  The "local"
    nature of the interaction is something that society has worked
    hard to construct.  Latour thus gives architecture and other human
    artifacts a central role in his sociology.  Sociology, in other words,
    in not simply "social" -- that is, it is not exclusively concerned
    with interactions among people, but instead locates those interactions
    in the artefactual world.  Architecture and design, likewise, are
    now understood as being very much embedded in an institutional order.
    
    Karla Hoff and Joseph E. Stiglitz, Modern economic theory and
    development, in Gerald M. Meier and Joseph E. Stiglitz, eds, Frontiers
    of Development Economics: The Future in Perspective, New York:
    Oxford University Press, 2001.  Joseph Stiglitz is an economist
    of information who has, in recent years, been heavily involved in
    the institutions of practical economics, for example during his time
    as chief economist of the World Bank.  His central argument is that
    problems of information force important revisions in the neoclassical
    picture of efficient market as a mediator of supply and demand.
    In his recent work, he has increasingly applied this argument
    to institutional problems such as those encountered by developing
    economies.  It is well-known that some of Stiglitz's neoclassical
    colleagues often presuppose the existence of economic and political
    institutions that many societies do not have.  Stiglitz's policy
    advice, by contrast, starts with the necessity of building such
    institutions alongside the market mechanisms that it is hoped
    they will eventually enable.  In this paper, Stiglitz and Karla Hoff
    survey the new research area of formalizing economic and political
    institutions in much the same way that economists have historically
    formalized efficient market mechanisms.  People who believe that
    institutions should be studied in their full qualitative detail will
    find these models overly simple.  And indeed nobody should be using
    them uncritically in setting policies.  Even so, formalism can be
    an important method of research when it is directed at the right
    object, and the institutional substrate of the economy is one of the
    most important objects of study right now.
    
    Daniel Beunza and David Stark, Tools of the trade: The socio-technology
    of arbitrage in a Wall Street trading room, working paper available at:
    http://www.stern.nyu.edu/mgt/seminars/downloads/tools_of_the_trade.pdf
    This is an excellent study of the ecology of knowledge in the
    arbitrage department of a large investment bank.  Arbitrage means
    making money by noticing and using inconsistencies between different
    markets.  If apples sell for 10 cents uptown and 20 cents downtown,
    you can make money by buying applies uptown, shipping them downtown,
    and selling them.  At least that is a simple example.  In the real
    world, arbitrage means operating simultaneously in numerous markets
    whose relationships are much harder to reckon than the relative
    costs of apples.  To reckon profitably, the investment bank needs to
    assemble teams with diverse forms of advanced knowledge of particular
    markets, and they need to design transactions that balance out every
    factor except for the one where the opportunity for profit lies.
    To do this, the bank puts tremendous thought in the physical work
    arrangements in their trading room.  For example, they deliberately
    migrate people around the room so that they will be working nearby
    others with varying types of skill, thus ensuring that skills are
    continually being mixed in new ways.  This is not the market as a
    form of virtual reality, but quite the contrary a socially distributed
    type of calculation that is very much embedded in arrangements in the
    physical world.
    
    Ken Alder, Making things the same: Representation, tolerance and the
    end of the Ancien Regime in France, Social Studies of Science 28(4),
    1998, pages 499-545.  Mass manufacture based on interchangeable
    parts arose in a quite different way in France than in the United
    States.  It happened in the context of the French Revolution,
    and in the transformation of an existing social system rather
    than the construction of a new one.  Interchangeable parts need to
    be manufactured according to precise tolerances, and this in turn
    requires a local social system in which that kind of precision can
    be reliably and consistently produced.  Alder describes the role
    played in this process by particular forms of representation, namely
    projective drawings as opposed to other free-hand, perspectival,
    and other sorts of drawings.  These drawings, together with fixtures,
    gauges, and other artefacts, were as central a part of the social
    system as any other.  Alder concludes his paper with a case study
    of a particular artisanal community whose whole way of life changed
    as part and parcel of this larger process of technological and
    institutional change.  Like all of the other papers I have reviewed
    here, Alder's paper provides an outstandingly valuable perspective
    on the ways that "local" and "global", "physical" and "virtual",
    interact in the adoption of important new technologies.
    
    end
    



    This archive was generated by hypermail 2b30 : Fri May 09 2003 - 18:32:09 PDT